Writing in the Financial Post, Macdonald-Laurier Institute Senior Fellow Philip Cross uses a recent MLI report to explain why the economic model known as Zero Dollar Linda helps explain social mobility in Canada and debunk the Great Gatsby Curve. “The lesson of Zero Dollar Linda is that incentives matter”, writes Cross.
The MLI report, by former Chief Statistician Munir Sheikh, demonstrates that many tax-transfer programs intended to address income inequality have been decreasing social mobility for low-income Canadians.
By Philip Cross, April 10, 2015
There always was something fishy about the so-called Great Gatsby curve, which holds that countries with more income inequality will experience less mobility among income classes. Its literary metaphor misrepresents the Scott Fitzgerald novel (Gatsby doesn’t inherit his wealth), while its economics relies on a limited sample and a poor understanding of the dynamics of inter-generational mobility.
Now a recently released Macdonald-Laurier Institute paper by Munir Sheikh, the former Chief Statistician of Canada, sheds more light on the weak thinking behind the Great Gatsby curve. Sheikh uses the concept of “Zero Dollar Linda,” a term coined by John Stapleton to describe a hypothetical recipient of government social assistance who decides that it is not worth working because of the many government benefits lost as her earned income increases (Zero Dollar Linda is not to be confused with the latest book sales report for crackpot author and NDP activist Linda McQuaig).
The lesson of Zero Dollar Linda is that incentives matter. Expanding the tax and transfer system to reduce income inequality as envisaged by proponents of the Great Gatsby curve ignores the impact these policies have on people’s incentives to escape low income, which may actually lower social mobility by trapping people behind a welfare wall. Empirically, the Zero Dollar Linda model does a better job of explaining social mobility than the Gatsby model. This implies that low social mobility among the poor is partly a creation of the very policies intended to help low income earners. It is fitting that Zero Dollar Linda should slay the Great Gatsby curve, which blames lower social mobility on market forces while ignoring the role of government policies.
This constant rate of mobility among classes means it’s impervious to attempts by government to influence mobility. And we’re not talking about relatively minor tinkering with variables like tax rates or education systems. Mobility rates were unaffected by revolutionary attempts to change society, including communist rule in China (Mao’s father was a rich farmer), the withdrawal of Japanese colonial rule in Korea, the outlaw of samurai privilege in Japan, the end of colonial rule and the caste system in India, and radical social changes in Chile. In the Western world, mobility rates were unaffected by the Industrial Revolution, the advent of representative democracy, redistributive taxation and mass education. That is serious stasis.
The Gatsby Curve is floundering as a result of several mistakes. Most importantly, it ignored incentives and distortions introduced by the tax and transfer system. It avoided long-term trends, which lowers measured mobility. And its exclusive focus on income as the only determinant of social structures downplays the latter’s true complexity, which originates in family and the inheritance of social status. It is simplistic to single out income to explain the relationship between generations. Several countries have confiscated the income of the rich, who nevertheless still transmit the most important advantage to their children — their genes. Nature dominates nurture; little inter-generational advantage is transmitted by access to resources. Maximizing the human capital you invest in your kids is largely wasted — you can email it in after passing on your genes. Clark estimates that equalizing the family environment for every child would change inter-generational outcomes by only a quarter.
Low mobility rates imply that outcomes for the rich and the poor will equalize eventually, but over 300 years not in one generation. Why does the upper stratum eventually fall back into the pack? People select mates partly on their social status and income, which has a random element related to luck. “The curse of the elite is that they are surrounded by imposters,” concludes Clark. The same is true for the lower class, which includes a portion of people with talented genes who, for whatever reason, slid down the status totem pole. Outcomes change only gradually, since they are embedded in dense social structures, not suddenly in response to government policy. To the degree that governments adopt income redistribution policies that inhibit economic growth, they hurt everyone while possibly hampering their goal of increased mobility.
Philip Cross is a Senior Fellow at the Macdonald-Laurier Institute and the former Chief Economic Analyst at Statistics Canada